Philosophers tried to specify a "bundle" or "package" of goods, services, and intangibles (like information, or skills, or knowledge). Justice - though not necessarily happiness - is when everyone possesses an identical bundle. Happiness - though not necessarily justice - is when each one of us possesses a "bundle" which reflects his or her preferences, priorities, and predilections. None of us will be too happy with a standardized bundle, selected by a committee of philosophers - or bureaucrats, as was
case under communism.The market allows for
exchange of goods and services between holders of identical bundles. If I seek books, but detest oranges - I can swap them with someone in return for his books. That way both of us are rendered better off than under
strict egalitarian version.
Still, there is no guarantee that I will find my exact match - a person who is interested in swapping his books for my oranges. Illiquid, small, or imperfect markets thus inhibit
scope of these exchanges. Additionally, exchange participants have to agree on an index: how many books for how many oranges? This is
price of oranges in terms of books.
Money -
obvious "index" - does not solve this problem, merely simplifies it and facilitates exchanges. It does not eliminate
necessity to negotiate an "exchange rate". It does not prevent market failures. In other words: money is not an index. It is merely a medium of exchange and a store of value. The index - as expressed in terms of money - is
underlying agreement regarding
values of resources in terms of other resources (i.e., their relative values).
The market - and
price mechanism - increase happiness and welfare by allowing people to alter
composition of their bundles. The invisible hand is just and benevolent. But money is imperfect. The aforementioned Rawles demonstrated (1971), that we need to combine money with other measures in order to place a value on intangibles.
The prevailing market theories postulate that everyone has
same resources at some initial point (the "starting gate"). It is up to them to deploy these endowments and, thus, to ravage or increase their wealth. While
initial distribution is equal -
end distribution depends on how wisely - or imprudently -
initial distribution was used.
Egalitarian thinkers proposed to equate everyone's income in each time frame (e.g., annually). But identical incomes do not automatically yield
same accrued wealth. The latter depends on how
income is used - saved, invested, or squandered. Relative disparities of wealth are bound to emerge, regardless of
nature of income distribution.
Some say that excess wealth should be confiscated and redistributed. Progressive taxation and
welfare state aim to secure this outcome. Redistributive mechanisms reset
"wealth clock" periodically (at
end of every month, or fiscal year). In many countries,
law dictates which portion of one's income must be saved and, by implication, how much can be consumed. This conflicts with basic rights like
freedom to make economic choices.
The legalized expropriation of income (i.e., taxes) is morally dubious. Anti-tax movements have sprung all over
world and their philosophy permeates
ideology of political parties in many countries, not least
USA. Taxes are punitive: they penalize enterprise, success, entrepreneurship, foresight, and risk assumption. Welfare, on
other hand, rewards dependence and parasitism.