Is Our Money Safe? - Part I

Written by Sam Vaknin


Banks are institutions where miracles happen regularly. We rarely entrust our money to anyone but ourselves – and our banks. Despite a very chequered history of mismanagement, corruption, false promises and representations, delusions and behavioural inconsistency – banks still succeed to motivate us to give them our money. Partly it isrepparttar feeling that there is safety in numbers. The fashionable term today is "moral hazard". The implicit guarantees ofrepparttar 106725 state and of other financial institutions move us to take risks which we would, otherwise, have avoided. Partly it isrepparttar 106726 sophistication ofrepparttar 106727 banks in marketing and promoting themselves and their products. Glossy brochures, professional computer and video presentations and vast, shrine-like, real estate complexes all serve to enhancerepparttar 106728 image ofrepparttar 106729 banks asrepparttar 106730 temples ofrepparttar 106731 new religion of money.

But what is behind all this? How can we judgerepparttar 106732 soundness of our banks? In other words, how can we tell if our money is safely tucked away in a safe haven?

The reflex is to go torepparttar 106733 bank's balance sheets. Banks and balance sheets have been both invented in their modern form inrepparttar 106734 15th century. A balance sheet, coupled with other financial statements is supposed to provide us with a true and full picture ofrepparttar 106735 health ofrepparttar 106736 bank, its past and its long-term prospects. The surprising thing is that – despite common opinion – it does.

But it is rather useless unless you know how to read it.

Financial statements (Income – or Profit and Loss - Statement, Cash Flow Statement and Balance Sheet) come in many forms. Sometimes they conform to Western accounting standards (the Generally Accepted Accounting Principles, GAAP, orrepparttar 106737 less rigorous and more fuzzily worded International Accounting Standards, IAS). Otherwise, they conform to local accounting standards, which often leave a lot to be desired. Still, you should look for banks, which make their updated financial reports available to you. The best choice would be a bank that is audited by one ofrepparttar 106738 Big Four Western accounting firms and makes its audit reports publicly available. Such audited financial statements should consolidaterepparttar 106739 financial results ofrepparttar 106740 bank withrepparttar 106741 financial results of its subsidiaries or associated companies. A lot often hides in those corners of corporate holdings.

Banks are rated by independent agencies. The most famous and most reliable ofrepparttar 106742 lot is Fitch Ratings. Another one is Moody’s. These agencies assign letter and number combinations torepparttar 106743 banks that reflect their stability. Most agencies differentiaterepparttar 106744 short term fromrepparttar 106745 long term prospects ofrepparttar 106746 banking institution rated. Some of them even study (and rate) issues, such asrepparttar 106747 legality ofrepparttar 106748 operations ofrepparttar 106749 bank (legal rating). Ostensibly, all a concerned person has to do, therefore, is to step up torepparttar 106750 bank manager, muster courage and ask forrepparttar 106751 bank's rating. Unfortunately, life is more complicated than rating agencies would have us believe.

They base themselves mostly onrepparttar 106752 financial results ofrepparttar 106753 bank rated as a reliable gauge of its financial strength or financial profile. Nothing is further fromrepparttar 106754 truth.

Admittedly,repparttar 106755 financial results do contain a few important facts. But one has to look beyondrepparttar 106756 naked figures to getrepparttar 106757 real – often much less encouraging – picture.

The Revolt of the Poor - The Demise of Intellectual Property

Written by Sam Vaknin


Three years ago I published a book of short stories in Israel. The publishing house belongs to Israel's leading (and exceedingly wealthy) newspaper. I signed a contract which stated that I am entitled to receive 8% ofrepparttar income fromrepparttar 106724 sales ofrepparttar 106725 book after commissions payable to distributors, shops, etc. A few months later (1997), I wonrepparttar 106726 coveted Prize ofrepparttar 106727 Ministry of Education (for short prose). The prize money (a few thousand DMs) was snatched byrepparttar 106728 publishing house onrepparttar 106729 legal grounds that allrepparttar 106730 money generated byrepparttar 106731 book belongs to them because they ownrepparttar 106732 copyright.

Inrepparttar 106733 mythology generated by capitalism to pacifyrepparttar 106734 masses,repparttar 106735 myth of intellectual property stands out. It goes like this: ifrepparttar 106736 rights to intellectual property were not defined and enforced, commercial entrepreneurs would not have taken onrepparttar 106737 risks associated with publishing books, recording records, and preparing multimedia products. As a result, creative people will have suffered because they will have found no way to make their works accessible torepparttar 106738 public. Ultimately, it isrepparttar 106739 public which paysrepparttar 106740 price of piracy, goesrepparttar 106741 refrain.

But this is factually untrue. Inrepparttar 106742 USA there is a very limited group of authors who actually live by their pen. Only select musicians eke out a living from their noisy vocation (most of them rock stars who own their labels - George Michael had to fight Sony to do just that) and very few actors come close to deriving subsistence level income from their profession. All these can no longer be thought of as mostly creative people. Forced to defend their intellectual property rights andrepparttar 106743 interests of Big Money, Madonna, Michael Jackson, Schwarzenegger and Grisham are businessmen at least as much as they are artists.

Economically and rationally, we should expect thatrepparttar 106744 costlier a work of art is to produce andrepparttar 106745 narrower its market -repparttar 106746 more emphasized its intellectual property rights.

Consider a publishing house.

A book which costs 50,000 DM to produce with a potential audience of 1000 purchasers (certain academic texts are like this) - would have to be priced at a a minimum of 100 DM to recoup onlyrepparttar 106747 direct costs. If illegally copied (thereby shrinkingrepparttar 106748 potential market as some people will prefer to buyrepparttar 106749 cheaper illegal copies) - its price would have to go up prohibitively to recoup costs, thus driving out potential buyers. The story is different if a book costs 10,000 DM to produce and is priced at 20 DM a copy with a potential readership of 1,000,000 readers. Piracy (illegal copying) should in this case be more readily tolerated as a marginal phenomenon.

This isrepparttar 106750 theory. Butrepparttar 106751 facts are tellingly different. The lessrepparttar 106752 cost of production (brought down by digital technologies) -repparttar 106753 fiercerrepparttar 106754 battle against piracy. The biggerrepparttar 106755 market -repparttar 106756 more pressure is applied to clamp down on samizdat entrepreneurs.

Governments, from China to Macedonia, are introducing intellectual property laws (under pressure from rich world countries) and enforcing them belatedly. But where one factory is closed on shore (as has beenrepparttar 106757 case in mainland China) - two sprout off shore (as isrepparttar 106758 case in Hong Kong and in Bulgaria).

But this defies logic:repparttar 106759 market today is global,repparttar 106760 costs of production are lower (withrepparttar 106761 exception ofrepparttar 106762 music and film industries),repparttar 106763 marketing channels more numerous (half ofrepparttar 106764 income of movie studios emanates from video cassette sales),repparttar 106765 speedy recouping ofrepparttar 106766 investment virtually guaranteed. Moreover, piracy thrives in very poor markets in whichrepparttar 106767 population would anyhow not have paidrepparttar 106768 legal price. The illegal product is inferior torepparttar 106769 legal copy (it comes with no literature, warranties or support). So why shouldrepparttar 106770 big manufacturers, publishing houses, record companies, software companies and fashion houses worry?

The answer lurks in history. Intellectual property is a relatively new notion. Inrepparttar 106771 near past, no one considered knowledge orrepparttar 106772 fruits of creativity (art, design) as "patentable", or as someone's "property". The artist was but a mere channel through which divine grace flowed. Texts, discoveries, inventions, works of art and music, designs - all belonged torepparttar 106773 community and could be replicated freely. True,repparttar 106774 chosen ones,repparttar 106775 conduits, were honoured but were rarely financially rewarded. They were commissioned to produce their works of art and were salaried, in most cases. Only withrepparttar 106776 advent ofrepparttar 106777 Industrial Revolution wererepparttar 106778 embryonic precursors of intellectual property introduced but they were still limited to industrial designs and processes, mainly as embedded in machinery. The patent was born. The more massiverepparttar 106779 market,repparttar 106780 more sophisticatedrepparttar 106781 sales and marketing techniques,repparttar 106782 biggerrepparttar 106783 financial stakes -repparttar 106784 larger loomedrepparttar 106785 issue of intellectual property. It spread from machinery to designs, processes, books, newspapers, any printed matter, works of art and music, films (which, at their beginning were not considered art), software, software embedded in hardware, processes, business methods, and even unto genetic material.

Intellectual property rights - despite their noble title - are less aboutrepparttar 106786 intellect and more about property. This is Big Money:repparttar 106787 markets in intellectual property outweighrepparttar 106788 total industrial production inrepparttar 106789 world. The aim is to secure a monopoly on a specific work. This is an especially grave matter in academic publishing where small- circulation magazines do not allow their content to be quoted or published even for non-commercial purposes. The monopolists of knowledge and intellectual products cannot allow competition anywhere inrepparttar 106790 world - because theirs is a world market. A pirate in Skopje is in direct competition with Bill Gates. When he sells a pirated Microsoft product - he is depriving Microsoft not only of its income, but of a client (=future income), of its monopolistic status (cheap copies can be smuggled into other markets), and of its competition-deterring image (a major monopoly preserving asset). This is a threat which Microsoft cannot tolerate. Hence its efforts to eradicate piracy - successful in China and an utter failure in legally-relaxed Russia.

But what Microsoft fails to understand is thatrepparttar 106791 problem lies with its pricing policy - not withrepparttar 106792 pirates. When faced with a global marketplace, a company can adopt one of two policies: either to adjustrepparttar 106793 price of its products to a world average of purchasing power - or to use discretionary differential pricing (as pharmaceutical companies were forced to do in Brazil and South Africa). A Macedonian with an average monthly income of 160 USD clearly cannot afford to buyrepparttar 106794 Encyclopaedia Encarta Deluxe. In America, 50 USD isrepparttar 106795 income generated in 4 hours of an average job. In Macedonian terms, therefore,repparttar 106796 Encarta is 20 times more expensive. Eitherrepparttar 106797 price should be lowered inrepparttar 106798 Macedonian market - or an average world price should be fixed which will reflect an average global purchasing power.

Something must be done about it not only fromrepparttar 106799 economic point of view. Intellectual products are very price sensitive and highly elastic. Lower prices will be more than compensated for by a much higher sales volume. There is no other way to explainrepparttar 106800 pirate industries: evidently, atrepparttar 106801 right price a lot of people are willing to buy these products. High prices are an implicit trade-off favouring small, elite, select, rich world clientele. This raises a moral issue: arerepparttar 106802 children of Macedonia less worthy of education and access torepparttar 106803 latest in human knowledge and creation?

Cont'd on page 2 ==>
 
ImproveHomeLife.com © 2005
Terms of Use